Investors Hangout Stock Message Boards Logo
  • Mailbox
  • Favorites
  • Boards
    • The Hangout
    • NASDAQ
    • NYSE
    • OTC Markets
    • All Boards
  • Whats Hot!
    • Recent Activity
    • Most Viewed Boards
    • Most Viewed Posts
    • Most Posted
    • Most Followed
    • Top Boards
    • Newest Boards
    • Newest Members
  • Blog
    • Recent Blog Posts
    • Recently Updated
    • News
    • Stocks
    • Crypto
    • Investing
    • Business
    • Markets
    • Economy
    • Real Estate
    • Personal Finance
  • Market Movers
  • Interactive Charts
  • Login - Join Now FREE!
  1. Home ›
  2. Stock Message Boards ›
  3. User Boards ›
  4. Traders Cafe Message Board

When Tariffs Worked Brian Domitrovic Contr

Message Board Public Reply | Private Reply | Keep | Replies (0)                   Post New Msg
Edit Msg () | Previous | Next


Post# of 27292
(Total Views: 75)
Posted On: 07/29/2018 5:54:59 PM
Avatar
Posted By: john1234
Re: dw #6839
When Tariffs Worked

Brian Domitrovic Contributor i
Mar 9, 2018, 07:45pm

The tariffs the United States is imposing on imports of aluminum and steel recall a sturdy American tradition. The tariff was the main form of federal taxation over the first half of the history of this country, until the income tax emerged in 1913. There is an indisputable chronological correlation between the tariff and phenomenal economic growth. From the late 18th to the early 20th twentieth centuries, the United States steadily developed into the most successful economy in the world.

Surely this correlation is not simple but real. Systems of taxation are ordinarily highly determinative of economic outcomes. The question that confronts us as the tariff issue thrusts itself upon us today is not if the tariff assisted the great era of economic growth the past, but how it did.

The first notable aspect of the tariff during its heyday over a century ago is that it was not general but specific. A tax on all imported goods went by the name “impost,” whose etymology implies a stamp, such a rubber device to mark an invoice with. If there were one rate of tax on all imported goods, say 5% ad valorem, a 5% stamp could be mass produced for all the customs houses. Customs collectors would impress or “impost” in ink any container list with the stamp as the amount due to the federal government.

The etymology of the old-Arabic-derived “tariff” implies a “list.” The tariff is not a general tax on imports, but an itemization of specific imports that are subject to customs duties, each of these duties a particular rate not capable of being made into a common stamp. Where the tax base of an impost is broad and its rate low and uniform, the tax base of a tariff is narrower and its rates variable and high.



It would appear that an impost is more economically efficient. James Madison thought as much when he proposed the first bill in Congress in the spring of 1789, a customs measure that essentially provided for an impost. He was rudely awakened. Madison’s fellow Members of Congress insisted on a tariff that blocked out imports of pet industries whose agents were funding their lifestyles as Senators and Representatives. A tariff along these lines, not Madison’s cleaner impost, became the first law of any consequence passed under the auspices of the Constitution, on July 4, 1789.

One of Madison’s famous remarks was that “if men were angels no government would be necessary.” In his impost defeat, Madison got to see that the new federal government had no intention of even masquerading as an angel. Via the tariff, Congress presented itself starkly as a favor-trading factory.

It is perhaps difficult for us to see how essential to American economic growth it was for Madison to have lost in this way in 1789. At the very outset of this nation’s Constitutional order, by means of the tariff, Congress offered itself to the public as venal and corrupt. This is surely one of the reasons—perhaps the major reason—that government remained so small over the entire era of the tariff.

From 1789 to 1913, the size of the federal government in the economy as a whole averaged about 3%, with variation in time of war. Today, that number is over 20%—a 7-fold increase. State and local government was another 3% back then, and is another 12% today. Where total government was 6% of economic output in the era of the tariff, it is five times larger at over 30% today.

A reason government was small under the tariff was that it was widely understood that government and its functionaries are objectionable. The tariff communicated this lesson inherently and explicitly. Because the tariff was a list displaying cronyism and making no play for being enlightened or fair, it did not demand respect. The quid pro quo the populace made with the tariff is that Congress and its conspirators in business got their favors, but in turn Congress’s realm, the government, had to stay small.

Therefore, the private economy was free to survey immense horizons. Boundless growth at the hands of entrepreneurs and a talented and ambitious workforce built up year after year as Congress got to curry its petty favors on the condition that government stayed limited in size.

The second essential aspect of the tariff during its heyday concerned receipts. Debates surrounding the tariff always inquired whether it was “for revenue” or “prohibitive.” These terms were ubiquitous in Congressional dronings on the tariff, the tariff easily being the most discussed political issue, slavery included, in America from 1789-1913, even in the antebellum period.

A tariff “for revenue” was one where a rate was set low enough for the good in question to flow into the country in sufficient quantity to bring in increasing receipts to the government. A “prohibitive” tariff was one that was so high, receipts would go up if a rate were lowered. The “Laffer curve” concept was the most discussed theorem in political-economic debates in the United States in the 19th century.

A tariff for revenue was that minimally tolerable to the public. A prohibitive tariff not only raised the cost of living; it also required further tax impositions to make up for the lost revenue. When Congressmen suggested prohibitive tariffs, they had to resort to stratagems. In the 1880s, Congress suggested that prohibitive tariffs were good because they yielded government less money, and government was bad. In the 1820s, pro-tariff Northerners had the votes, so they were relieved of having to justify a prohibitive tariff to South Carolina. This was one of the reasons South Carolina felt less and less need to move away from its slave economy on ethical grounds.

After the income tax was put in place in 1913, the tariff shed its revenue purpose and became exclusively a vehicle for cronyism. Therefore it got very high—so high, in 1930, that it shut out imports that were responsible for financing upwards of a fifth of the American banking system’s loan portfolio. That system was ruined and the result was the Great Depression.

The tariff worked in the past because its manifest horridness made it impossible for a government that adopted it to have a claim on size and respectability. In this context, the private—the real—economy had capacious room to operate and boomed like no economy before or since. As we contemplate tariffs today, we should seek to institute them, for revenue, as our sole means of taxation

source
https://www.forbes.com/sites/briandomitrovic/...fa196970f9



(0)
(0)








Investors Hangout

Home

Mailbox

Message Boards

Favorites

Whats Hot

Blog

Settings

Privacy Policy

Terms and Conditions

Disclaimer

Contact Us

Whats Hot

Recent Activity

Most Viewed Boards

Most Viewed Posts

Most Posted Boards

Most Followed

Top Boards

Newest Boards

Newest Members

Investors Hangout Message Boards

Welcome To Investors Hangout

Stock Message Boards

American Stock Exchange (AMEX)

NASDAQ Stock Exchange (NASDAQ)

New York Stock Exchange (NYSE)

Penny Stocks - (OTC)

User Boards

The Hangout

Private

Global Markets

Australian Securities Exchange (ASX)

Euronext Amsterdam (AMS)

Euronext Brussels (BRU)

Euronext Lisbon (LIS)

Euronext Paris (PAR)

Foreign Exchange (FOREX)

Hong Kong Stock Exchange (HKEX)

London Stock Exchange (LSE)

Milan Stock Exchange (MLSE)

New Zealand Exchange (NZX)

Singapore Stock Exchange (SGX)

Toronto Stock Exchange (TSX)

Contact Investors Hangout

Email Us

Follow Investors Hangout

Twitter

YouTube

Facebook

Market Data powered by QuoteMedia. Copyright © 2025. Data delayed 15 minutes unless otherwise indicated (view delay times for all exchanges).
Analyst Ratings & Earnings by Zacks. RT=Real-Time, EOD=End of Day, PD=Previous Day. Terms of Use.

© 2025 Copyright Investors Hangout, LLC All Rights Reserved.

Privacy Policy |Do Not Sell My Information | Terms & Conditions | Disclaimer | Help | Contact Us